翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Stolp Starduster Too
・ Stolp Synagogue
・ Stolp Woolen Mill Store
・ Stolpe
・ Stolpe (Berlin)
・ Stolpe Abbey
・ Stolpe an der Peene
・ Stolpe auf Usedom
・ Stolpe, Parchim
・ Stolpe, Schleswig-Holstein
・ Stolpen
・ Stolper
・ Stolper See
・ Stolperstein
・ Stolpersteine in the district of Braunau am Inn
Stolper–Samuelson theorem
・ STOLport
・ Stolpsee
・ Stolsbergi
・ Stolsvatnet
・ Stolt
・ Stolt Anne
・ Stolt Herr Alf
・ Stolt-Nielsen
・ Stolte
・ Stoltebüll
・ Stoltenberg
・ Stoltenberg (Norwegian family)
・ Stoltenberg (surname)
・ Stoltenberg I Cabinet


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Stolper–Samuelson theorem : ウィキペディア英語版
Stolper–Samuelson theorem
The Stolper–Samuelson theorem is a basic theorem in Heckscher–Ohlin trade theory. It describes the relationship between relative prices of output and relative factor rewards—specifically, real wages and real returns to capital.
The theorem states that—under specific economic assumptions (constant returns, perfect competition, equality of the number of factors to the number of products)—a rise in the relative price of a good will lead to a rise in the return to that factor which is used most intensively in the production of the good, and conversely, to a fall in the return to the other factor.
==History==
It was derived in 1941 from within the framework of the Heckscher–Ohlin model by Wolfgang Stolper and Paul Samuelson,〔.〕 but has subsequently been derived in less restricted models. As a term, it is applied to all cases where the effect is seen. Ronald W. Jones and José Scheinkman (1977) show that under very general conditions the factor returns change with output prices as predicted by the theorem. If considering the change in real returns under increased international trade a robust finding of the theorem is that returns to the scarce factor will go down, ceteris paribus. An additional robust corollary of the theorem is that a compensation to the scarce factor exists which will overcome this effect and make increased trade Pareto optimal.〔J. Peter Neary, "(History of the Theorem )", (Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, 2004).〕
The original Heckscher–Ohlin model was a two-factor model with a labour market specified by a single number. Therefore, the early versions of the theorem could make no predictions about the effect on the unskilled labour force in a high-income country under trade liberalization. However, more sophisticated models with multiple classes of worker productivity have been shown to produce the Stolper–Samuelson effect within each class of labour: Unskilled workers producing traded goods in a high-skill country will be worse off as international trade increases, because, relative to the world market in the good they produce, an unskilled first world production-line worker is a less abundant factor of production than capital.
The Stolper–Samuelson theorem is closely linked to the factor price equalization theorem, which states that, regardless of international factor mobility, factor prices will tend to equalize across countries that do not differ in technology.

抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Stolper–Samuelson theorem」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.